1.
Both total output and output per worker have risen strongly over time in
the United States. Output itself has grown by a factor of 100 in the last 133
years. Output per worker is now six times as great as it was in 1900. These
changes have led to a much higher standard of living today.
9.
Classicals see wage and price adjustment occurring rapidly, while
Keynesians think that wages and prices adjust only slowly when the economy is
out of equilibrium. The classical theory implies that unemployment will not
persist because wages and prices adjust to bring the economy rapidly back to
equilibrium. But if Keynesian theory is correct, then the slow response of wages
and prices means that unemployment may persist for long periods of time unless
the government intervenes.
1. (a)
Average labor productivity is output divided by employment:
2005: 12,000
tons of potatoes divided by 1000 workers =
12 tons of potatoes per worker
2006: 14,300
tons of potatoes divided by 1100 workers =
13 tons of potatoes per worker
(b) The growth rate of average labor
productivity is [(13/12) – 1]
´ 100% = 8.33%.
(c) The unemployment rate is:
2005: (100 unemployed/1100 workers)
´ 100% = 9.1%
2006: (50 unemployed/1150 workers)
´ 100% = 4.3%
(d) The inflation rate is [(2.5/2) –
1]
´
100% = 25%.
5. Given data: I
= 40, G
= 30, GNP = 200,
CA = –20
= NX
+ NFP,
T = 60, TR = 25,
INT = 15, NFP
=
7 –9
= –2. Since
GDP =
GNP – NFP, GDP
= 200 – (–2)
= 202
= Y.
Since NX +
NFP = CA,
NX =
CA – NFP
= –20 – (–2)
= –18. Since Y
= C +
I + G
+ NX, C
= Y – (I
+ G +
NX)
= 202 – (40 +
30 + (–18))
= 150.
Spvt = (Y
+ NFP – T
+ TR + INT)
– C = (202
+ (–2) – 60
+ 25 +
15) –150 = 30. Sgovt
= (T – TR – INT)
– G = (60 – 25 – 15) – 30 =
–10. S = Spvt
+ Sgovt
= 30 +
(–10) = 20.
(a) Consumption
= 150
(b) Net exports
=
–18
(c) GDP
=
202
(d) Net factor payments
from abroad = –2
(e) Private saving
= 30
(f)
Government saving = –10
(g) National saving
= 20
6.
Base-year quantities at current-year prices |
|
at base-year prices |
|
Apples |
3000
´ $3
= $ 9,000 |
|
3000
´ $2
= $ 6,000 |
Bananas |
6000
´ $2 = $12,000 |
|
6000
´ $3 = $18,000 |
Oranges |
8000
´ $5 =
$40,000 |
|
8000
´ $4 =
$32,000 |
Total |
$61,000 |
|
$56,000 |
Current-year quantities at current-year prices |
|
at base-year prices |
|
Apples |
4,000
´ $3 = $ 12,000 |
|
4,000
´ $2 = $ 8,000 |
Bananas |
14,000
´ $2 = $ 28,000 |
|
14,000
´ $3 = $ 42,000 |
Oranges |
32,000
´
$5 = $160,000 |
|
32,000
´ $4 =
$128,000 |
Total |
$200,000 |
|
$178,000 |
(a) Nominal GDP is just the dollar
value of production in a year at prices in that year. Nominal GDP is $56
thousand in the base year and $200 thousand in the current year. Nominal GDP
grew 257% between the base year and the current year: [($200,000/$56,000) – 1]
´ 100% = 257%.
(b) Real GDP is calculated by finding
the value of production in each year at base-year prices.
Thus, from the table above, real GDP is
$56,000 in the base year and $178,000 in the current year. In percentage
terms, real GDP increases from the base year to the current year by
[($178,000/$56,000) – 1]
´ 100% = 218%.
(c) The GDP deflator is the ratio of
nominal GDP to real GDP. In the base year, nominal GDP equals real GDP, so the
GDP deflator is 1. In the current year, the GDP deflator is $200,000/$178,000
= 1.124. Thus the GDP deflator changes
by [(1.124/1) – 1]
´
100% = 12.4% from the base year to the
current year.
(d) Nominal GDP rose 257%, prices
rose 12.4%, and real GDP rose 218%, so most of the increase in nominal GDP is
because of the increase in real output, not prices. Notice that the quantity of
oranges quadrupled and the quantity of bananas more than doubled.
1. The key to this
question is that real GDP is not the same thing as well-being. People may be
better off even if real GDP is lower; for example, this may occur because the
improvement in the health of workers is more valuable to society than the loss
of GDP due to the regulation. Ideally, we would like to be able to compare the
costs and benefits of such regulations; they should be put in place if the
overall costs (the reduced GDP in this case) are valued less than the overall
benefits (the workers’ health).
3. (a)
The problem in a planned economy is that prices do not measure market
value. When the price of an item is too low, then goods are really more
expensive than their listed price suggests—we should include in their market
value the value of time spent by consumers waiting to make purchases. Because
the item’s value exceeds its cost, measured GDP is too low.
When the price of an item is too high, goods stocked on the shelves may be
valued too highly. This results in an overvaluation of firms’ inventories, so
that measured GDP is too high.
A possible strategy for dealing with this problem is to have GDP analysts
estimate what the market price should be (perhaps by looking at prices of the
same goods in market economies) and use this “shadow” price in the GDP
calculations.
(b) The goods and services that
people produce at home are not counted in the GDP figures because they are not
sold on the market, making their value difficult to measure. One way to do it
might be to look at the standard of living relative to a market economy, and
estimate what income it would take in a market economy to support that standard
of living.